Al-Jazeerah: Cross-Cultural Understanding
www.ccun.org www.aljazeerah.info |
Opinion Editorials, September 2012 |
||||||||||||||||||
Archives Mission & Name Conflict Terminology Editorials Gaza Holocaust Gulf War Isdood Islam News News Photos Opinion Editorials US Foreign Policy (Dr. El-Najjar's Articles) www.aljazeerah.info
|
The Myth That Japan Is Broke:
Al-Jazeerah, CCUN, September 8, 2012
Japan’s massive government debt conceals massive benefits for the Japanese
people, with lessons for the U.S. debt “crisis.”
In an April 2012 article in Forbes titled “If
Japan Is Broke, How Is It Bailing Out Europe?”, Eamonn Fingleton pointed
out
the Japanese government was by far the largest single non-eurozone
contributor to the latest Euro rescue effort.
This, he said, is “the same government that has been going round
pretending to be bankrupt (or at least offering no serious rebuttal when
benighted American and British commentators portray Japanese public finances
as a trainwreck).” Noting that
it was also Japan that rescued the IMF system virtually single-handedly at
the height of the global panic in 2009, Fingleton asked: How can a nation whose government is supposedly the most
overborrowed in the advanced world afford such generosity? . . . The betting is that Japan’s true public finances are far
stronger than the Western press has been led to believe. What is undeniable
is that the Japanese Ministry of Finance is one of the most opaque in the
world . . . . Fingleton acknowledged that the Japanese government’s
liabilities are large, but said we also need to look at the asset side of
the balance sheet: [T]he Tokyo Finance Ministry is increasingly borrowing
from the Japanese public not to finance out-of-control government spending
at home but rather abroad. Besides stepping up to the plate to keep the IMF
in business, Tokyo has long been the lender of last resort to both the
U.S. and British governments. Meanwhile it borrows 10-year money at an
interest rate of just 1.0 percent, the second lowest rate of any borrower in
the world after the government of Switzerland. It’s a good deal for the Japanese
government: it can borrow 10-year money at 1 percent and lend it to the U.S.
at 1.6 percent (the going rate on
U.S. 10-year bonds),
making a tidy spread.
Japan’s debt-to-GDP ratio is nearly 230%,
the worst of any major country in the world.
Yet
Japan
remains the world’s largest
creditor country,
with net foreign assets of $3.19 trillion.
In 2010, its GDP per capita
was more than that of France, Germany, the U.K. and Italy.
And while China’s economy is now larger than
Japan’s because of its burgeoning population (1.3 billion versus 128
million), China’s $5,414 GDP per capita is only 12 percent of Japan’s
$45,920. How to explain these
anomalies?
Fully 95 percent of Japan’s national debt
is held domestically by the Japanese themselves.
Over 20% of the debt is
held by Japan Post Bank, the Bank of Japan, and other government entities.
Japan Post is the
largest holder of domestic savings in the world, and it returns interest to
its Japanese customers.
Although theoretically privatized in 2007, it
has been a political football, and 100% of its stock is still owned by the
government.
The Bank of Japan is 55% government-owned and
100% government-controlled.
Of the remaining debt, over
60% is held by
Japanese banks, insurance companies and pension funds.
Another chunk is held by individual Japanese savers.
Only 5% is held by
foreigners, mostly central banks.
As noted in a September 2011
article in The New York Times:
The Japanese government is in deep debt, but the rest of Japan has ample
money to spare. The Japanese government’s debt
is
the people’s money.
They own each other, and they collectively
reap the benefits.
Myths of the Japanese Debt-to-GDP Ratio Japan’s debt-to-GDP ratio looks
bad.
But
as economist Hazel Henderson notes,
this is just a matter of accounting practice—a practice that she and other
experts contend is misleading.
Japan leads globally in most areas of
high-tech manufacturing, including aerospace.
The debt on the other side of its balance
sheet represents the payoffs from all this productivity to the Japanese
people.
According to Gary Shilling,
writing on
Bloomberg in June
2012, more than half of Japanese public spending goes for debt service and
social security payments.
Debt
service is paid as interest to Japanese “savers.”
Social security and interest on the national
debt are not included in GDP, but these are actually the social safety net
and public dividends of a highly productive economy.
These, more than the military weapons and
“financial products” that compose a major portion of U.S. GDP, are the real
fruits of a nation’s industry.
For Japan, they represent the enjoyment by the
people of the enormous output of their high-tech industrial base.
Shilling writes: Government
deficits are supposed to stimulate the economy, yet the composition of
Japanese public spending isn’t particularly helpful. Debt service and
social-security payments -- generally non-stimulative -- are expected to
consume 53.5 percent of total outlays for 2012 . . . . So says conventional theory, but
social security and interest paid to domestic savers actually do stimulate
the economy.
They do it by getting money into the pockets
of the people, increasing “demand.”
Consumers with money to spend then fill the
shopping malls, increasing orders for more products, driving up
manufacturing and employment.
Myths About Quantitative Easing Some of the money for these
government expenditures has come directly from “money printing” by the
central bank, also known as “quantitative easing.”
For over a decade, the Bank of Japan has been
engaged in this practice; yet the hyperinflation that deficit hawks said it
would trigger has not occurred.
To the contrary, as noted by
Wolf Richter in a May 9, 2012 article: [T]he Japanese [are] in fact among the few people in the
world enjoying actual price stability, with interchanging periods of minor
inflation and minor deflation—as opposed to the 27% inflation per decade
that the Fed has conjured up and continues to call, moronically, “price
stability.” He cites as evidence the following graph from the
Japanese Ministry of Internal Affairs:
How
is that possible?
It all depends on where the money generated by
quantitative easing ends up.
In Japan, the money borrowed by the government
has found its way back into the pockets of the Japanese people in the form
of social security and interest on their savings.
Money in consumer bank accounts stimulates
demand, stimulating the production of goods and services, increasing supply;
and when supply and demand rise together, prices remain stable.
Myths About
the “Lost Decade”
Japan’s finances have long been shrouded in secrecy, perhaps because when
the country was more open about printing money and using it to support its
industries, it got
embroiled in World War II.
In his
2008 book
In the Jaws of the Dragon,
Fingleton suggests that Japan feigned insolvency in the “lost decade” of the
1990s to avoid drawing the ire of protectionist Americans for its booming
export trade in automobiles and other products.
Belying the weak reported statistics, Japanese
exports increased by 73% during that decade, foreign assets increased, and
electricity use increased by 30%, a tell-tale indicator of a flourishing
industrial sector.
By 2006, Japan’s exports were three times what
they were in 1989.
The
Japanese government has maintained the façade of complying with
international banking regulations by “borrowing” money rather than
“printing” it outright.
But borrowing money issued by the government’s
own central bank is the functional equivalent of the government printing it,
particularly when the debt is just carried on the books and never paid back.
Implications
for the “Fiscal Cliff” All
of this has implications for Americans concerned with an out-of-control
national debt.
Properly managed and directed, it seems, the
debt need be nothing to fear.
Like Japan, and unlike Greece and other
Eurozone countries, the U.S. is the sovereign issuer of its own currency.
If it wished, Congress could fund its budget
without resorting to foreign creditors or private banks.
It could do this either by issuing the money
directly or by borrowing from its own central bank, effectively
interest-free, since the Fed rebates its profits to the government after
deducting its costs.
A little quantitative easing can be a good thing, if the money winds up with
the government and the people rather than simply in the reserve accounts of
banks. The national debt can
also be a good thing.
As Federal Reserve Board
Chairman Marriner
Eccles testified in hearings before the House Committee on Banking and
Currency in 1941, government credit (or debt) “is what our money system is.
If there were no debts in our money system, there wouldn’t be any
money.”
Properly directed, the national debt becomes the spending money of the
people.
It stimulates demand, stimulating productivity.
To keep the system stable and sustainable, the
money just needs to come from the nation’s own government and its own
people, and needs to return to the government and people.
_______________________ Ellen
Brown is an attorney and president of the Public Banking Institute,
http://PublicBankingInstitute.org.
In Web of Debt, her latest of eleven books, she shows how a
private cartel has usurped the power to create money from the people
themselves, and how we the people can get it back. Her websites are
http://WebofDebt.com and
http://EllenBrown.com.
|
|
Opinions expressed in various sections are the sole responsibility of their authors and they may not represent Al-Jazeerah & ccun.org. |